Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Hysteresis and persistent long-term unemployment: the American Beveridge Curve of the Great Depression and World War II

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Cliometrica Aims and scope Submit manuscript

The results are striking: the interwar United States is characterized by pure hysteresis, with a completely insignificant [unemployment] level effect.

Gordon and Schultze (1988, p. 300)

Hysteresis appears to be an important feature of American depression.

Blanchard and Summers (1986, p. 69)

Abstract

Long-term unemployment plagued the American economy of the Great Depression. The stigma of a long unemployment spell made reentering employment difficult even during the brisk economic recovery, which lead to unemployment hysteresis and persistently high joblessness. Unemployment figures disaggregated by duration confirm the importance of hysteresis for the Great Depression, as the long-term unemployed were less likely to return to gainful employment until the war. Using the theoretical framework of the Beveridge Curve, I find that hysteresis was a significant problem during the 1930s, but that the essentially unlimited labor demand during the World War II provided jobs even to the long-term unemployed. As a result, labor market conditions in the 1950s resembled those of the 1920s prior to the Depression and so the labor market scars of the Great Depression were healed.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The situation would undoubtedly worsen by later in the decade, though data are not available from Buffalo to examine this possibility.

  2. “Works managers in Greenwich testified that even a short period of unemployment handicapped a man in his efforts to market his labour. There was, first of all, the preference that the employer had for the man who had just come from a job. In all probability he would be more competent than a man who had been away from his tools for some period. The handicap increased with the length of time out of work. ...[T]he complaint was made even among the labourers that the man just out of a job was given the preference. ...The general impression among the men was that the chances of getting a job were inversely proportional to the number of men who had come out since they were discharged” (Bakke 1933, pp. 50–51).

  3. Blanchard and Wolfers (2000) provide an overview of these arguments and a strong case for the interaction between adverse shocks and inflexible labor market institutions. Ljungqvist and Sargent (1998) provide an example of a structuralist view on the European unemployment problem of the 1980s.

  4. See Table 1 for some evidence to this effect from Philadelphia.

  5. This curve is often attributed to Beveridge (1944), though it is not explicitly defined in that book and should perhaps instead be attributed to Dow and Dicks-Mireaux (1958) where the unemployment–vacancy relationship is discussed at length.

  6. The economist John Cochrane voiced support for this view in a recent interview: “When we discover we made too many houses in Nevada some people are going to have to move to different jobs, and it is going to take them a while of looking to find the right job for them. There will be some unemployment” (Cassidy 2010).

  7. In the 1930s an example would be the numerous jobs available in agriculture in California, while farmers could not find work in states affected by the Dust Bowl (Gregory 1991) or more recently the example of steelworkers in Pittsburgh who must become nurses in a different city (Shimer 2007).

  8. Unemployment benefits only begin at the state level in Wisconsin in 1932 and at the national level in 1935, so this would not have played much of a role in the early phases of the Depression (Price 1985).

  9. See Baldwin (1988), Dixit (1989), Franz (1990), Dixit (1992), Feinberg (1992), and Cross (1993).

  10. See Friedman (1968), Phelps (1967, 1968), Blanchard and Katz (1997), Ball and Gregory Mankiw (2002).

  11. See (Kendrick 1961, p. 320).

  12. Labor unions lobbied the Roosevelt administration to block job retraining programs for those hired on emergency job programs like the WPA as there were already too few jobs for the skilled union workers that made up their membership (Jensen 1989, p. 577).

  13. Note that both theories will generate hysteresis in unemployment as an inpulse to the unemployment rate will tend to persist due to this discrimination on the part of employers.

  14. I do not stress the term structural unemployment as the many long-term unemployed are in some sense structurally unemployed, as there are reasons other than current business cycle conditions impeding their employment. However, with sustained labor demand for such a large magnitude even the long-term unemployed will be hired, so they represent an intermediate case. As argued in Standing (1983), discussions of structural unemployment in this context are often muddled and unclear.

  15. This effect can be seen in the ranking model of Blanchard and Diamond (1994). A model of stigma for the long-term unemployed is presented in Vishwanath (1989), which predicts lower exit rates from unemployment for the long-term unemployed.

  16. If there were data on hiring rates for the period and if the assumption of a stable unemployment rate was satisfied, then a matching efficiency term could be derived, which would define an isoquant.

  17. Note that there are no discouraged workers here, and any nonemployed “gainful” worker counts as unemployed even if they are not actively seeking employment.

  18. To complicate things further, the Census Bureau performed the direct work of conducting the survey.

  19. Weir (1992) revisits these estimates and improves upon the Lebergott series.

  20. The likely possibility of procyclical labor force participation also figures prominently in Romer (1986)’s argument for spurious volatility in unemployment rates.

  21. For robustness, I include alternatives to the BCP estimates from the Conference Board series in the form of the American Federation of Labor monthly unemployment series and the author’s own calculations of a monthly unemployment rate. The results are little changes by the choice of unemployment rate.

  22. 1937–1938 was a sharp but brief recessionary period which does not seem to have lasted long enough to have had a significant hysteretic effect.

  23. The shift in priorities from creating more employment to deal with a surplus a unemployed workers, which was the problem of the 1930s, to the priority of creating more war material given a rapidly diminishing pool of surplus or unemployed workers in the early 1940s, makes for a stark contrast. The possibilities for increasing war production using the unemployed and any available worker are discussed extensively in the reports of the Office of War Mobilization and Reconversion.

  24. Diamond and Şahin (2015) argue that this means that shifts in the Beveridge Curve are not very informative about structural changes in the economy in terms of a natural rate of unemployment, but these regular shifts related to the business cycle can be adequately explained by a hysteresis-based explanation such as the one presented in this paper.

  25. The choice of using a was dictated to smooth out noise while minimizing the distortion of the underlying series. This method is preferred to seasonal adjustment due to issue related to seasonal adjustment as discussed in Wright (2013). A 7-month moving average, symmetric with three months on either side of the center month, was chosen visually to smooth seasonal variation without eliminating trends.

  26. Concerns about veterans returning to high postwar unemployment were prominent among the framers of the GI Bill, which subsidized education for veterans which also kept them from the labor force for a few years (Olson 1973). Lawrence Klein was able to successfully forecast a rapid postwar recovery due to pent-up demand in sectors like consumer durables before the GI BIll was passed, so unemployment likely would have remained low even without the GI Bill (Woytinsky 1947).

  27. In the interest of brevity and a lack of data on duration, I do not discuss racial differences in employment prospects, though twice of many blacks as white were unemployed in Philadelphia for both genders, and they would have faced both discrimination based on both race and unemployment duration, making their prospects even more dire (Palmer 1938, p. 22).

  28. The recovery period is marred by the sharp but brief 1937–1938 recession.

References

  • Abraham KG, Wachter M (1987) Help-wanted advertising, job vacancies, and unemployment. Brook Pap Econ Act 1:207–248

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D (1995) Public policy in a model of long-term unemployment. Economica 62(246):161–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • AFL (1936) The federation’s revised unemployment estimate. In: William G (ed) American Federationist vol 43. American Federation of Labor, Washington, DC

  • Ahn HJ, Hamilton JD (2014) Heterogeneity and unemployment dynamics. University of California, San Diego Working Paper

  • Arulampalam W, Gregg P, Gregory M (2001) Unemployment scarring. Econ J 111(475):577–584

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bakke EW (1933) The unemployed man. E. P. Dutton & Co, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin R (1988) Hysteresis in import prices: the Beachhead effect. Am Econ Rev 78(4):773–785

    Google Scholar 

  • Ball LM (2009) Hysteresis in unemployment: old and new evidence. NBER Working Paper (14818)

  • Ball LM, Gregory MN (2002) The NAIRU in theory and practice. J Econ Perspect 16(4):115–136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ball L, Gregory Mankiw N, Nordhaus WD (1999) Aggregate demand and long-run unemployment. Brook Pap Econ Act 1999(2):189–251

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barnichon R (2010) Building a composite help-wanted index. Econ Lett 109(3):175–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barnichon R, Elsby M, Hobijn B, Sahin A (2012) Which industries are shifting the beveridge curve. Monthly Lab Rev 135:25

    Google Scholar 

  • Benjamin DK, Kochin LA (1979) Searching for an explanation of unemployment in interwar Britain. J Polit Econ 87(3):441–478

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beveridge WH (1944) Full employment in a free society. George Allen And Unwin Ltd, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Biewen M, Steffes S (2010) Unemployment persistence: is there evidence for stigma effects? Econ Lett 106(3):188–190

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard OJ, Summers LH (1986) Hysteresis and the European unemployment problem. NBER macroeconomics annual 1986, vol 1. MIT Press, Cambridge, pp 15–90

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard OJ, Summers LH (1987) Hysteresis in unemployment. Eur Econ Rev 31(1):288–295

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard OJ, Diamond PA (1990) The beveridge curve. NBER working paper, (R1405)

  • Blanchard OJ, Diamond PA (1994) Ranking, unemployment duration, and wages. Rev Econ Stud 61(3):417–434

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard O, Katz LF (1997) What we know and do not know about the natural rate of unemployment. J Econ Perspect 11(1):51–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard OJ, Wolfers J (2000) The role of shocks and institutions in the rise of European unemployment: the aggregate evidence. Econ J 110(462):1–33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bordo MD, Erceg CJ, Evans CL (2000) Money, sticky wages, and the great depression. Am Econ Rev 90(5):1447–1463

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cassidy J (2010) Interview with John Cochrane. The New Yorker. http://www.newyorker.com/news/john-cassidy/interview-with-john-cochrane

  • Clague E (1935) The problem of unemployment and the changing structure of industry. J Am Stat Assoc 30(189):209–214

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cole HL, Ohanian LE (1999) The great depression in the united states from a neoclassical perspective. Fed Reserve Bank Minneap Q Rev 23:2–24

    Google Scholar 

  • Congress United States (May 12 1944a) First report of the house special committee on post-war economic policy and planning

  • Congress United States (August 14 1944b) third report of the house special committee on post-war economic policy and planning

  • Crafts NF (1989) Long-term unemployment and the wage equation in Britain, 1925–1939. Economica 56(222):247–254

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cross R (1993) On the foundations of hysteresis in economic systems. Econ Philos 9(01):53–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daly MC, Hobijn B, Şahin A, Valletta RG (2012) A search and matching approach to labor markets: did the natural rate of unemployment rise? J Econ Perspect 26(3):3–26

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Darby MR (1976) Three-and-a-half million U.S. employees have been mislaid: or, an explanation of unemployment, 1934–1941. J Polit Econ 84(1):1–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond PA, Şahin A (2015) Shifts in the Beveridge curve. Res Econ 69(1):18–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Director, War Mobilization and Reconversion (October 1946a) Eighth report to the president, the senate, and the house of representatives

  • Director, War Mobilization and Reconversion (April 1946b) Sixth report to the president, the senate, and the house of representatives

  • Dixit A (1989) Hysteresis, import penetration, and exchange rate pass-through. Q J Econ 104(2):205–228

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit A (1992) Investment and hysteresis. J Econ Perspect 6(1):107–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doppelt R (2014) The hazards of unemployment. New York university working paper

  • Dow JCR, Dicks-Mireaux LA (1958) The excess demand for labour. A study of conditions in Great Britain, 1946–56. Oxford Econ Pap 10(1):1–33

  • Dynarski M, Sheffrin SM (1990) The behavior of unemployment durations over the cycle. Rev Econ Stat 72(2):350–356

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elsby MWL, Hobijn B, Şahin A (2010) The labor market in the great recession. Brookings papers on economic activity, Economic studies program, The Brookings Institution, vol 41(1(Spring)), pp 1–69

  • Entorf H (1994) Overtime work, lack of labour, and structural mismatch: some extensions of the european unemployment programme framework. Output and employment fluctuations. Springer, Berlin, pp 131–156

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Eriksson S, Rooth DO (2014) Do employers use unemployment as a sorting criterion when hiring? Evidence from a field experiment. Am Econ Rev 104(3):1014–1039

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Faberman J, Kudlyak M (2014) The intensity of job search and search duration. Technical Report, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

  • Farber HS (2011) Job loss in the great recession: historical perspective from the displaced workers survey, 1984–2010. Technical Report, National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Farber HS, Valletta RG (2015) Do extended unemployment benefits lengthen unemployment spells? Evidence from recent cycles in the US labor market. J Hum Resour 50(4):873–909

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feinberg RM (1992) Hysteresis and export targeting. Int J Ind Organ 10(4):679–684

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franz W (1990) Hysteresis in economic relationships: an overview. Springer, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman M (1968) The role of monetary policy. Am Econ Rev 48(1):1–17

    Google Scholar 

  • Ghayad R (2013a) A decomposition of shifts of the Beveridge curve. Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Working Paper

  • Ghayad R (2013b) The jobless trap. Technical Report, Northeastern Working Paper

  • Gibbons R, Katz LF (1991) Layoffs and lemons. J Labor Econ 9(4):351–380

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon RJ (1989) Hysteresis in history: was there ever a Phillips curve? Am Econ Rev 79(2):220–225

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon RJ, Schultze CL (1988) Back to the future: European unemployment today viewed from America in 1939. Brook Pap Econ Act 1988(1):271–312

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon RJ, Krenn R (2010) The end of the Great Depression 1939–41: policy contributions and fiscal multipliers. Technical Report, National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Gregory JN (1991) American exodus: the dust bowl migration and Okie culture in California. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Hagedorn M, Karahan F, Manovskii I, Mitman K (2013) Unemployment benefits and unemployment in the great recession: the role of macro effects. Technical Report, National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Hansen AH (1939) Economic progress and declining population growth. Am Econ Rev 29(1):1–15

    Google Scholar 

  • Heckman JJ (1991) Identifying the hand of past: distinguishing state dependence from heterogeneity. Am Econ Rev 81(2):75–79

    Google Scholar 

  • Isaac AG (1994) Hysteresis. In: Arestis P, Sawyer MC (eds) The Elgar companion to radical political economy. Edward Elgar, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Jackman R, Layard R (1991) Does long-term unemployment reduce a person’s chance of a job? A time-series test. Economica 58(229):93–106

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackman R, Savouri S (1999) Mismatch: a framework for thought. Tackling unemployment. Springer, Berlin, pp 141–200

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Jackman R, Pissarides C, Savouri S, Kapteyn A, Lambert J-P (1990) Labour market policies and unemployment in the OECD. Econ Policy 5(11):449–490

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jarosch G, Pilossoph L (2015) Statistical discrimination and duration dependence in the job finding rate

  • Jensen RJ (1989) The causes and cures of unemployment in the Great Depression. J Interdisc Hist 19(4):553–583

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katz LF, Meyer BD (1990) The impact of the potential duration of unemployment benefits on the duration of unemployment. J Public Econ 41(1):45–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kendrick JW (1961) Productivity trends in the United States. Productivity trends in the United States

  • Kocherlakota N (2010) Inside the FOMC. Speech at Marquette, Michigan

    Google Scholar 

  • Kroft K, Lange F, Notowidigdo MJ (2013) Duration dependence and labor market conditions: evidence from a field experiment*. Q J Econ 128(3):1123–1167

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Layard R, Nickell S, Jackman R (2005) Unemployment: macroeconomic performance and the labour market. OUP Catalogue

  • Lebergott S (1964) Manpower in economic growth: the American record since 1800. McGraw-Hill, New York

  • Lindbeck A, Snower DJ (1988) The insider-outsider theory of employment. Unemployment, Cambridge

  • Ljungqvist L, Sargent TJ (1998) The European unemployment dilemma. J Political Econ 106(3):514–550

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lonigan E (1939) The effect of modern technological conditions upon the employment of labor. Am Econ Rev 29(2):246–259

    Google Scholar 

  • Machin S, Manning A (1999) The causes and consequences of longterm unemployment in Europe. Handb Labor Econ 3:3085–3139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Margo RA (1991) The microeconomics of depression unemployment. J Econ Hist 51(02):333–341

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mathy G (2016) A monthly unemployment rate series for American states: 1930–1975

  • Nakamura E (2008) Layoffs and lemons over the business cycle. Econ Lett 99(1):55–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • National Industrial Conference Board (1940) Employment and unemployment of the labor force 1900–1940. vol 2, No. 8, pp 89–92

  • Nickell S (1997) Unemployment and labor market rigidities: Europe versus North America. J Econ Perspect 11(3):55–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nickell S, Layard R (1999) Labor market institutions and economic performance. Handb Labor Econ 3:3029–3084

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nickell S, Nunziata L, Ochel W, Quintini G (2003) The Beveridge Curve, unemployment and wages in the OECD from the 1960s to the 1990s. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Nixon RA, Samuelson PA (1940) Estimates of unemployment in the United States. Rev Econ Stat 22(3):101–111

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oberholzer-Gee F (2008) Nonemployment stigma as rational herding: a field experiment. J Econ Behav Organ 65(1):30–40

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson KW (1973) The GI Bill and higher education: success and surprise. Am Q 25(5):596–610

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palmer GL (1937)Recent trends in employment and unemployment in Philadelphia. Works Progress Administration, National Research Project on Reemployment Opportunities and Recent Changes in Industrial Techniques

  • Palmer GL (1938) Employment and unemployment in Philadelphia 1936 and 1937. Works Progress Administration, National Research Project on Reemployment Opportunities and Recent Changes in Industrial Techniques

  • Petrongolo B, Pissarides CA (2001) Looking into the black box: a survey of the matching function. J Econ Lit 39(2):390–431

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Phelps ES (1967) Phillips curves, expectations of inflation and optimal unemployment over time. Economica 34(135):254–281

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Phelps ES (1968) Money-wage dynamics and labor-market equilibrium. J Polit Econ 76(4 Part 2):678–711

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Phelps ES (1994) Structural slumps: the modern equilibrium theory of unemployment, interest, and assets. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Pissarides CA (1992) Loss of skill during unemployment and the persistence of employment shocks. Q J Econ 107(4):1371–1391

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pissarides CA (2000) Equilibrium unemployment theory. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Price DN (1985) Unemployment insurance, then and now, 1935–85. Soc Secur Bull 48(10):23

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogers CL (1997) Job search and unemployment duration: Implications for the spatial mismatch hypothesis. J Urban Econ 42(1):109–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer C (1986) Spurious volatility in historical unemployment data. J Polit Econ 94(1):1–37

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roosevelt FD (1936) Correspondence to Mr. Carl Byoir

  • Sahin A, Song J, Topa G, Violante GL (2014) Mismatch unemployment. Am Econ Rev 104(11):3529–64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shimer R (2007) Mismatch. Am Econ Rev 97(4):1074–1101

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Standing G (1983) Notion of structural unemployment. Int Lab Rev 122:137

    Google Scholar 

  • Summers LH (2014) US economic prospects: secular stagnation, hysteresis, and the zero lower bound. Bus Econ 49(2):65–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van den Berg GJ, Van Ours JC (1996) Unemployment dynamics and duration dependence. J Labor Econ 14(1):100–125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vishwanath T (1989) Job search, stigma effect, and escape rate from unemployment. J Labor Econ 7(4):487–502

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wallis JJ (1989) Employment in the Great Depression: new data and hypotheses. Explor Econ Hist 26(1):45–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weir DR (1992) A century of us unemployment, 1890–1990: revised estimates and evidence for stabilization. Res Econ Hist 14(1):301–46

    Google Scholar 

  • Winslow HJ (1938) The effect of a shortened waiting period on unemployment benefit costs. Soc Secur Bull 2(1):20

    Google Scholar 

  • Woirol GR (1996) The technological unemployment and structural unemployment debates, number 173, Greenwood Publishing Group

  • Woytinsky WS (1940) Additional workers and the volume of unemployment in the depression. Committee on social security, Social science research council, Washington, DC

  • Woytinsky WS (1942) Three aspects of labor dynamics: a report prepared for the committee on social security. Committee on social security, Social science research council, Washington

  • Woytinsky WS (1947) What was wrong in forecasts of postwar depression? J Polit Econ 55(2):142–151

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • WPA (1947) Final report on progress of the WPA program

  • Wright JH (2013) Unseasonal seasonals? Brook Pap Econ Act 2013(2):65–126

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zagorsky JL (1998) Job vacancies in the United States: 1923 to 1994. Rev Econ Stat 80(2):338–345

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The support of the Institute for New Economic Thinking and the ALL-UC Economic History Association is much appreciated. Many thanks go to Eric DeLisle for his invaluable assistance in the Social Security Administration Archives and to Diego Garcia and John Escobar for their research assistance.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Gabriel P. Mathy.

Additional information

Larry Ball, Jon Faust, Martha Starr, Evan Kraft, Bob Feinberg, Alan Isaac, John Parman, Henry Hyatt, and seminar audiences at Johns Hopkins, George Mason University, the College of William and Mary, the Census Bureau, the Social Science History Association, the Southern Economic Association Meetings, and American University provided useful comments.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Mathy, G.P. Hysteresis and persistent long-term unemployment: the American Beveridge Curve of the Great Depression and World War II. Cliometrica 12, 127–152 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11698-016-0158-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11698-016-0158-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation